In February this year the WHO Director General, Margaret Chan caused a storm when she was quoted in Thailand saying that the country should negotiate with pharmaceutical companies before issuing a compulsory license. She encouraged the nation’s public health ministry to improve its relationship with drug companies to strike the right balance in accessing drugs. Chan’s statement created the impression that there was something wrong with compulsory licensing that needed to be corrected through negotiating with pharmaceutical companies.
If the comments were meant to shock and awe, they achieved exactly that! Shocked treatment access advocates sought clarification from the DG herself on the alleged statements. Five days after the comments appeared in the Bangkok Post of February 2, civil society received information that a letter was dispatched to Thai’s Minister of Health, Mongkol Na Songkhla. There had been a misunderstanding, the Director General said. She regretted that her comments “were misrepresented in the media, and may have caused embarrassment to the government of Thailand. They should not be taken as criticism of the decision of the Royal Thai government to issue compulsory licences which is entirely the prerogative of the government, fully in line with the TRIPS agreement.”
For the avoidance of doubt, the Director General went on to say the following:
"WHO unequivocally supports the use by developing countries of the flexibilities within the TRIPS agreement that ensure access to affordable, high quality drugs. This includes the use of compulsory licensing, as described in paragraph 6 of the Doha Declaration on the TRIPS Agreement and Public Health. The decision whether to issue a compulsory license for a pharmaceutical product is a national one. There is no requirement for countries to negotiate with patent holders before issuing a compulsory licence."
This statement helped to clarify an impression that pharmaceutical companies have higher priority than people’s lives. For Africa this is particularly important, with Southern Africa the epicentre of the global HIV epidemic with 34 % of global AIDS deaths occurring in the region. While AIDS places a heavy burden on households and health systems generally, the cost of treatment for AIDS continues to be disproportionate to the incomes of affected families and of governments.
According to Oxfam reports, prices of some treatment regimens for AIDS are on the rise. This is saddening evidence coming six years after the historic signing of the Doha Declaration on TRIPS and Public Health in 2001. Fierce generic competition has helped prices for first-line AIDS drug regimen to fall by 99% from $10,000 to roughly $130 per patient per year since 2000. However prices for second-line drugs remain high due to increased patent barriers in key generics producing countries like India. Patients who develop resistance to first line regimens need these second line drugs, and the number is likely to grow over time, as will the unaffordable cost to health systems.
As outlined in the EQUINET / SEATINI leaflet on using TRIPS flexibilities (at www.equinetafrica.org) countries have full authority under TRIPS to use compulsory licensing or parallel importation of drugs if their laws provide for this and they need them for public health., Most (but not all) countries in the region have now passed the relevant laws for this. But the political and diplomatic pressure to dissuade governments from using these TRIPS flexibilities keeps mounting. A case in point is the legal action against the Indian government by a pharmaceutical company, Novartis. Novartis is challenging a section of India's Patents Act that aims to restrict certain kinds of patents. Novartis brought a civil lawsuit against the Indian government after the country rejected in January 2006 the company's attempt to patent a new version of its leukaemia drug, Gleevec, on the basis that the drug is a new formulation of an existing drug. If Novartis wins the case it could potentially set a precedent for other pharmaceutical companies seeking patent protection for formulations of drugs made before 1995, including antiretrovirals.
As institutions involved in health in Africa, we expect no ambiguity on this from WHO. Governments should be encouraged to use the flexibilities provided to them in the WTO TRIPS Agreement, including issuing compulsory licenses, to access generic drugs. With the Global Fund for AIDS, TB and Malaria and UNAIDS, still more needs to be done to bring down the cost of these drugs, particularly of the second line regimens, and to make them affordable on a long term basis.
For our part, we expect our governments and parliaments to ensure that our national laws incorporate TRIPs flexibilities, that our authorities are organised to implement them and that our populations are organised to protect their use. We expect our governments to reject clauses in bilateral trade agreements that attempt to remove authority to use these flexibilities. We have regional intergovernmental organisations such as COMESA and SADC to share information, resources and expertise and to harmonise legislation.
We can also stimulate the production and marketing of generic drugs, increasing returns to producers and access for people who need them. We can work through these same regional organisations to collectively issue compulsory licenses for common public health problems. In Latin America, for example, ten countries joined efforts to get agreements from generic manufacturers and originators on generic drug production. If ESA countries use regional frameworks to collectively issue compulsory licenses for the same drug, this builds a large enough market to encourage producers to invest in producing cheaper, generic versions of these drugs.
Please send feedback or queries on the issues raised in this briefing to the EQUINET secretariat at TARSC, email admin@equinetafrica.org and please visit the SEATINI website at www.seatini.org. EQUINET work on health equity in economic and trade policy and further information on TRIPS flexibilities is available at the EQUINET website at www.equinetafrica.org.
Editorial
Are institutions that tap poor people’s desire for credit, shrinking Third World states’ already beleaguered welfare policies? The role of microfinance in poverty reduction, reducing risk environments for HIV and promoting private health insurance has attracted high profile interest since Muhammad Yunus won the Nobel Peace Prize last December.
Yunus’s Grameen Bank battled backward Bangladeshi patriarchal and religious attitudes to extend credit to millions of people. Poor women were typically arranged in groups of five: two got the first tranche of credit, leaving the other three as ‘chasers’ to pressure repayment, so they could in turn get the next loans. But a decade ago (at a time of lower foundation subsidies, new competitors, adverse weather conditions and a backlash by borrowers who used collective power of nonpayment), Grameen imposed dramatic price increases on loan repayments and resorted to extreme pressure techniques, including removing tin roofs from delinquent women’s houses. This reduced Grameen Bank’s main philosophical position - ‘We consider credit as a human right’ - to merely an argument for access, not affordability. This distinguishes Yunus from all rights-based social movements demanding ‘rights’ to free lifeline access to healthcare, AIDS medicines, education, housing, land, water, electricity, etc.
According to Munir Quddus, chair of the Department of Economics and Finance, University of Southern Indiana, the model needs more investigation: ‘The very nature of setting up groups leaves out the very poor who would be perceived by fellow members to have no ability to generate income and therefore high risk … microcredit simply deepens the exploitation of the women since the rates of interest charged by the bank in real [after inflation] terms are quite high; consequently, credit often worsens the debt situation and gives the husbands even more leverage.’
Evidence on South Asian microcredit and major credit programs suggest that credit does not necessarily have a positive impact on social relations. Many loans targeted at women are appropriated by male family members, leaving women as buffers between their spouses and lending institutions, with often stressful and violent results. Even where women’s incomes have increased, research found women’s work and debt loads also increased. Women’s access to credit does not guarantee improved confidence, mobility, control over assets, or freedom from violence. Therefore, microcredit must be interrogated to determine if it is really about poor people gaining control, or if it leaves structural and often global causes of poverty unaddressed.
For example, in 1998, when an emerging market crisis led to rising interest rates across the Third World, South African microlenders and borrowers were driven into bankruptcy by a 7% increase imposed over two weeks as the local currency crashed. In Zimbabwe, a 1980s US$66 million flood of World Bank financing revitalised the rural microfinance sector (initiated under 1940s Rhodesian rule) and reached 94,000 households. But within a decade, the peasant default rate was 80% - with repayment affordability being a huge factor (a typical lender’s overhead and collection costs on a small loan were 15-22% (including incorporation of a 4% default rate)). Michael Drinkwater’s (1991) detailed study of central Zimbabwe showed peasant farmers faced serious difficulties in servicing loans of just a few hundred US dollars, since average net crop profit was just $0.15/hour of labour, according to a 1989 Agriculture Ministry survey. This was compounded by ‘an overzealous launching of a group credit scheme’ and the ‘doubtful viability of high cost fertiliser packages’, inappropriate for the erratic climate. ‘The increase in credit use means farmers have to market more to stay solvent ... At the household level it is commonly debts not profits that are on the rise.’
This raises the question: ‘Is credit the most useful input for African peasants’ economic and social wellbeing, especially women?’ According to Mohindra and Haddad (2005), women’s health capabilities (opportunities to achieve good health) and health functionings (e.g. being healthy), ‘can be expanded via key determinants of population health, such as access to resources and autonomy’, with microcredit as a primary tool. But is microcredit really a tool for expanding access to health inputs when the structural disempowerment and malfunctioning markets that bedevil credit systems are added to the overall retreat of the Third World welfare state?
The question is important as Grameen-style microcredit is increasingly linked to health services ranging from education to insurance, including: the Niger CARE ‘Microcredit and Health Education for HIV/AIDS-Affected Women and Children in the Valley of the Widows’; the Philippine NGO Innovations for Poverty Action and the Green Bank marketing of health insurance and preventative care through 2000 microentrepreneurs; or
the International Medical Corps microcredit project to support local health programs in Eritrea. The Microcredit Campaign Summit pointed to many new opportunities to substitute microcredit for state or donor assistance in reproductive health education. But such schemes need to be questioned on: whether they deliver on resources and autonomy, how they change local power relations; and their record on arrears, social conflict and defaults.
Few rigorous studies document the relationships between financial vulnerability and health burdens. A study of a Dominican microcredit program, which made small loans to individuals to start or expand small businesses, included three communities: one with health promotion alone; one with microcredit alone; and one with both. The community with parallel microcredit and health promotion programs had the largest changes for ten of eleven health indicators. However, the study also traced health gains to improved ability to purchase commercial water supplies, making a link between microcredit and the demand on poor people to pay for commercial and privatised water. As the UNDP Human Development Report (2006) noted, microcredit is explicitly used to promote the market in essential services and enable poor households to meet the financing requirements.
While not denying the prospect that some microcredit schemes are worthy and effective, the criticisms raised offer warning. Claims made about microcredit as an overarching strategy to end poverty, change power relations, attack structures of inequality or improve vulnerable population’s health education should be treated with caution. Certainly, microcredit cannot stand in for decent social policy when it acts as a safety net, co-existing with and not transforming entrenched structures that generate poverty . In the worst case, microcredit can become an ideology explicitly hostile to state support for healthcare.
‘I believe that “government”, as we know it today, should pull out of most things except for law enforcement and justice, national defense and foreign policy, and let the private sector, a “Grameenized private sector”, a social-consciousness-driven private sector, take over their other functions.’
To illustrate the dangers ahead, those were words uttered in the 1998 autobiography of Nobel Peace Prize winner Yunus.
Please send feedback or queries on the issues raised in this briefing to the EQUINET secretariat at TARSC, email admin@equinetafrica.org. A more detailed analysis of the issues raised in this editorial can be found in Microcredit Evangelism, Health and Social Policy by Patrick Bond, Forthcoming in the International Journal of Health Services, June 2007.
On December 10 the Africa Public Health Rights Alliance launched an important “15% now!” campaign. We carry information on the campaign in this newsletter, and its call for African heads of state to allocate 15% on government spending to health, as promised at the African Union (AU) summit in Abuja, in 2001.
There is clear evidence of the pressing demand for significantly improved resources for health in east and southern Africa (ESA): We see it in high levels of poverty and deprivation, persistently high HIV, AIDS and other preventable diseases, high rates of child and early adult mortality, inadequately staffed and resourced public health services and massive inequalities in health outcomes between sub-Saharan Africa and other regions. The EQUINET newsletters in 2006 have presented different facets of this evidence. Health is determined by the conditions in which people live, work and interact, and depends on policies and spending beyond the health sector. The investments in the health sector are, however, critical, especially in the context of high levels of inequality and poverty. These investments can prevent avoidable illness and mortality, redistribute social resources to deprived households, protect against the impoverishing effects of ill health and demonstrate our values and commitment as a society to human security. As our May newsletter editorial suggests, health sector investments have greatest impact on low income communities when they are made in public sector primary health care and district health systems.
The World Health Organisation estimated in 2000 that an expenditure of US$60 per capita is the minimum level of health expenditure needed for a health system to function well. The Macroeconomic Commission on Health estimated in 2003 that a minimally adequate set of interventions to meet the basic health needs of poor communities is between US$34 and US$38 per person per year, not including some of the wider systems demands for a functional health system. However African health systems and communities face challenges that call for additional resources: The World Bank estimated in 2002 that Africa would need an additional US$4.2 billion to meet the costs of HIV prevention and AIDS Care, given the scale of the epidemic. Meeting the Millennium Development Goals (MDGs) adds to this cost. This makes an expenditure of US$60 per person per year a not unreasonable estimate, and one that would need to be made largely in the public sector if the benefits are to reach poor households.
Yet many public health sectors in ESA are trying to deliver health systems, pay health workers and respond to health challenges on less than $15 per person per year, and some on less than US$10 per year. Overall per capita expenditures on health in the region, public and private combined, average less than US$30 per person per year, while government spending on health is less than 10% total government spending for the majority of countries in the region.
Increasing to 15% of Government spending on health is an important and necessary sign of government commitment to health, even while it would not on its own for most countries in ESA provide adequate per capita resources for health. The call for “15% now!” justifiably calls for implementation of this commitment. If the 15% target is met through increased donor resources and not through increased application of domestic revenue, it is not a clear test of that commitment and is vulnerable to donor withdrawal. The “15% now” should thus be understood to exclude donor resources.
However, many countries in the region need more than the 15% government spending. Additional resources must be applied.
One of the sources for this must be debt cancellation. With over US$ 100 billion external debt in ESA in 2003 and even more paid out over three decades to service the debt, current debt relief measures are inadequate to overcome “debt domination”. Applied over many decades, with relatively small reductions in annual debt, they still leave African countries with significant debt burdens and deplete domestic resources for heath. As in last year’s call by civil society organisations and governments in the South-North consultation on alternatives to debt domination, the a call for “15% now!” must go together with a call for “Debt cancellation now!”.
Debt servicing is only one of the many ways resources are flowing out of our region. As demonstrated in the April EQUINET newsletter editorial, unfair and unequal terms of trade, outflows of private finance, shifts to speculative foreign investment, phantom aid, a massive outflows of health workers and global exploitation of non renewable African resources represent some of the vast and ongoing outflows of the continent’s existing and potential wealth. A recently released UN WIDER report included in this newsletter observes that inequalities in wealth have widened, with the richest 2% of adults in the world owning more than half of global household wealth, while the bottom half of the world adult population –a large share in Africa - own barely 1% of global wealth. Net outflows of African wealth represent a perverse flow of resources for health from those with greatest health needs in the poorest regions, to those with least health needs in the wealthiest regions.
This calls for a global response. An increase in predictable long term overseas development aid would provide one means of addressing this situation, and could be applied to increase the per capita spending on health to more meaningful levels, over and above the “15% now”. Efforts by some G8 countries to explore new sources of tax funding for global transfers are important steps towards this. So while African governments must be accountable for their 15% to health, so too wealthy countries must honour their commitment to “0.7% GDP to ODA now!”
But achieving global commitments to health in ESA calls for more than increased aid. Global commitments to universal access to antiretroviral treatment discussed in our June newsletter editorial, or the social development goals set at the 1995 World Summit for Social Development (WSSD), discussed in our November editorial, call for enabling, accessible, responsive and accountable states committed to mobilize the resources for health (15% now!), unencumbered by excessive debt servicing (Debt cancellation now!) and supported by ODA (0.7% GDP to ODA now!) Yet this can leave governments and people in ESA heavily reliant on external aid for their health, while wealthy groups in high income countries and corporates continue to benefit from trade, finance and resource outflows from the region. Levering increased investments in heath must be backed by challenge to these resource outflows and to the trade and macroeconomic policies that intensify inequities in control over the resources for health. “Reclaim African wealth for African health...now!”.
Please send feedback or queries on the issues raised in this editorial to the EQUINET secretariat at TARSC, email admin@equinetafrica.org
There have been dramatic changes to municipal services such as water and electricity since the end of apartheid in South Africa, with considerable research having gone into the impacts of commercialisation and cost recovery on low-income households. The research has revealed a complex and often negative relationship between the marketisation of these services and access and affordability for the poor. It has also been shown to have direct and very negative public health implications, most acutely in low-income township and rural areas.
Less obvious, and much less researched, have been the impacts of changes in service delivery on the mental health of low-income residents and household members. The fact that there is a relationship between poor mental health and poverty in general has now been well established. Common mental disorders (notably, anxiety and depression), while once thought to be the preserve of the rich who could afford the ‘luxury’ of worrying about emotional issues, have in fact been shown to have higher prevalence in low-income households. It has also been suggested that there is a cycle of vulnerability between poverty and marginalization, physical ill health, emotional distress, and mental disorder.
What, then, might be the links between poverty, mental health and the shift towards market-oriented reforms in basic services? A preliminary detailed ethnographic study of ten low-income families coping with a serious mental disorder (schizophrenia) in Cape Town pointed to several problems including:
• Health and safety problems. Household members have difficulties in ensuring appropriate use of medication (due to lack of water), practicing adequate hygiene, growing their own food, and with general comfort (such as being warm and dry). There are also concerns about being forced to use open fires, candles and paraffin stoves for cooking and warmth, leading to additional health and safety worries such as poisoning, fires, and respiratory infections.
• Time and energy. Considerable time and energy are spent searching for alternative sources of water and electricity and having to live with limited supplies of both.
• Social tensions. Respondents expressed concern with having to borrow money or water from neighbours and family members, leading to additional stresses in the lives of
household members and often to tensions within families and neighbourhoods, exacerbating the stigmas typically attached to mental disorders.
• Social activities. Reducing service consumption has implications for people’s social lives and household entertainment. Most of the households interviewed owned a television or radio, for example, but were reluctant to use them due to electricity costs. One family member reported being bored at home and therefore spending time with peers who encouraged him to use drugs. This has important implications for health, as co-morbid substance abuse has been shown to play a role in relapse of schizophrenia as well as being implicated in the onset of psychosis.
• Relapse. The stress of not being able to afford adequate services, or having these services cut off or restricted, would appear to add considerable stress to the person with the mental disorder, possibly contributing to a worsening of the disorder and/or a relapse.
• Impact on care-giving environment. Inadequate services would appear to increase levels of stress and burden for the caregiver(s), with implications for their own mental health. This then impacts on the family member with the mental disorder as well as the household as a whole, as the caregiver’s ability to care for the family may be compromised. Women appear to be the most affected by this as the primary caregivers.
Households experienced considerable financial hardship as a result of cost recovery strategies on basic services, with 29% of household income being spent on water and electricity on average, and arrears on water and electricity bills as high as R18 200. This situation caused anxiety and added considerably to overall family stress.
While households used a range of strategies to minimise water usage, the need to save water was a further source of anxiety and conflict. Similarly, concerns were raised about electricity usage and cut-offs, with disability grants being used to pay for fuel and basic services in many households.
While direct links between experiences of service delivery difficulties and the onset or relapse of mental disorder cannot be drawn, but it is clear that uncertainty about services in the context of poverty add to overall stress levels. Much remains to be done in terms of realising the rights of people with mental disorders (and their families) in South Africa. Without considering the broader context of poverty and service delivery it will not be possible for them to adequately improve their lives.
Editors comment: This issue of the newsletter presents material on mental health and equity, and we note the limited publication found in this area. EQUINET invites further contributions on mental health in Africa, and particularly in relation to equity issues. Please send contributions, feedback or queries on the issues raised in this briefing to the EQUINET secretariat, email admin@equinetafrica.org. Further information on issues raided in the briefing or the Municipal Services Project see http://www.queensu.ca/msp/ Greg Ruiters, Institute for Social and Economic Research, Rhodes University Grahamstown.
Editors Comment: In mid-December of 2005, the World Bank hosted a gathering of academics, policy analysts, policy makers and development practitioners at Arusha, Tanzania on the theme of New Frontiers of Social Policy. The meeting reviewed progress on commitments made at the 1995 World Summit for Social Development (WSSD). The Arusha meeting proposed a number of new frontiers for social policy: First the transformation of subjects and beneficiaries into citizens”, recognizing their rights and strengthening their capacity to claim these rights, including through alliances between the poor and other segments of society. The second new frontier of social policy was identified as fostering an enabling, accessible, responsive and accountable state, with institutional mechanisms that offer redress against power inequities. The third new frontier was identified as strengthening the capacity of states to mobilize revenue from their citizens, with enabling international support, diminishing reliance on external aid. The meeting called for greater emphasis on equity outcomes in social policy. Chan Chee Khoon, Professor of Health and Social Policy at Universiti Sains Malaysia comments on these meeting outcomes. An extended version of this paper has been accepted for publication in Global Social Policy and will be published by SAGE Publications in Global Social Policy 6(3) December 2006 - © SAGE Publications 2006. This shorter version has been produced for the EQUINET newsletter with permission from the author and Sage Publications
Notwithstanding the language and imagery of pioneering intellectual endeavor, my first (Anglophone) reaction to the Arusha statement was, déjà vu again? Just as Jeffrey Sachs and the WHO Commission on Macroeconomics and Health recycled human capital theory, so are we now revisiting Dudley Seers (The Meaning of Development), redistribution-with-growth, basic (human) needs, and other 1960s vintage wisdom recast in 21st century guise? What precisely is novel in the statement?
Novelty aside, three important points are noteworthy in the Arusha statement:
Firstly, it prominently endorsed a rights perspective, going beyond human needs. A rights perspective, it should be noted, can be accommodated or co-opted within a market-oriented approach. So for instance, Tony Blair and New Labor can declare that the de facto right-to-health of UK citizens is still intact even as German medical teams are brought in to attend to NHS patient backlogs, NHS patients are sent to France or India for treatment, NHS support services are outsourced to Kaiser Permanente, etc. In effect, this transforms the debate over state versus market, into a comparative assessment of the performance efficiencies of service providers, whether public, private, voluntary, for-profit, or some hybrid of these. Oddly, these debates often seem oblivious to parallel trends in fiscal reforms and the declining fiscal capacity of states, which the Arusha statement attempts to address through domestic mobilization of revenues.
Secondly, the Arusha statement endorsed a more embedded analysis of institutions, states, and other actors, in order to elucidate the success and failures of international development approaches to poverty reduction.
This is appropriate, indeed overdue. Going beyond states, it should also be extended to international organizations including the Bretton Woods institutions (BWIs). For instance, the World Bank has itself been subject to forces pushing for privatization (divesting its development lending role to private capital markets), much in the way that welfarist states are urged to selectively offload their more profitable (or commercially viable) social services to the private sector.
Challenged by the 2000 Meltzer Commission recommendations to cease lending to ‘credit worthy’ middle-income countries’(i.e. to stop competing with private lenders), the World Bank seems to have re-positioned itself as an even more influential promoter of the interests of private capital, even as it tries to harmonize this with “poverty reduction” (trickle down theory, a rising tide lifts all boats, what’s next? a sideways lurch towards horizontal equity?). We see, for instance, expanded roles for the International Finance Corporation (IFC) and the Multilateral Investment Guarantee Agency (MIGA) within the World Bank Group, with IFC and MIGA commitments to private sector borrowers rising from 3.3% of World Bank loans in 1980 to 25% in 2000. The World Bank Private Sector Development Strategy, 2002, (para. 87) emphasized the lead role of the Bank in insuring and catalyzing private investment in ‘more risky environments’ and in supporting ‘the development of cross-border private investment’ , crowding in (sic) ‘private investment rather than crowding it out’.
David de Ferranti, who retired in 2005 as World Bank vice-president for the Latin America and Caribbean department, found it necessary to reiterate that “much of what the World Bank actually does directly helps to improve the climate for private investment: implementing trade reforms and removing restrictive regulations on foreign direct investment; expanding private provision of utilities and infrastructure; strengthening essential legal and judicial infrastructure for private markets; freeing business from harmful and superfluous regulations” (cited in de Ferranti 2006. The World Bank and the Middle Income Countries, in Rescuing the World Bank ed. Nancy Birdsall Wash. DC,: Center for Global Development).
Thirdly, the Arusha statement quite rightly cautions against a targeted approach as an undiscriminating policy response to demonstrable social inequities in development. Thandika Mkandawire, UNRISD director, has recently authored an insightful review of universalism versus selectivity through targeting in social policy and development practice (Targeting and Universalism in Poverty Reduction. UNRISD Programme Paper Number 23. Geneva: 2005). He examines the circumstances and the forces behind the shift from universalism toward selectivity in social policy discourses addressing poverty in the developing countries. He then reviews the lessons learnt from such policy approaches and related practices: the administrative difficulties and transactional costs of targeting in the poor countries, the political economy bases of policy choices and program preferences, and the contingent and sometimes unpredictable effects of policy choices on individual incentive. In particular, he pays special attention to the cost-effectiveness argument which the advocates of selectivity deploy as a major consideration in its favour.
One aspect he does not dwell upon though is that targeting as a policy choice is eminently compatible with the concerns of influential sectors, including entrepreneurs and investors, seeking profitable opportunities in service sectors which thus far have been the domain of the public sector. The modern welfarist state acts importantly as a risk pooler in coping with uncertainty, whether arising from social, natural, or created environments. Publicly provided (or publicly financed) social services often entail cross-subsidies and risk pooling (in effect, an implicit social contract rooted in solidarity) to ensure a more equitable access to essential services than would be the case with purely market-driven production and distributional systems. With the devolution of social services to private enterprise, entrepreneurs in search of investment prospects would be primarily interested in the “market-capable” segments of society (if the state demurs from extending this effective demand, through public financing, to those without the disposable incomes).
Not surprisingly, as the flipside of privatization, voluntarism has emerged as a popular slogan, in rhetoric if not in substance, along with an ascendant neo-liberalism (George Bush Sr’s thousand points of lights, Mahathir’s caring society as counterpoint to Malaysia, Inc., etc). Social capital and civic society likewise are appealing to the World Bank as private capital proceeds to undermine a sense of community worldwide.
Seen in that light, targeting is also the persuasive face and generic template for the privatization of essential social services, persuasive because it draws upon considerable intuitive appeal. The intuitive appeal is not without reason, and targeting can in fact achieve quite positive results under certain favorable circumstances, e.g. when targeting is used to direct and to fine-tune extra benefits to low-income groups within the context of what are fundamentally universalist policies (targeting within universalism). As distinct from this however, targeting versus universalism has remained as the preferred policy axis for much of the international development establishment, prompting Thandika Mkandawire to observe that “one remarkable feature of the debate on universalism and targeting is the disjuncture between an unrelenting argumentation for targeting, and a stubborn slew of empirical evidence suggesting that targeting is not effective in addressing issues of poverty (as broadly understood)”.
Please send feedback or queries on the issues raised in this briefing to the EQUINET secretariat, email admin@equinetafrica.org. Further information and publication on EQUINET work on public health policy is available at the EQUINET website at www.equinetafrica.org.
Recent media attention in South Africa has drawn attention to an outbreak of Extreme Drug Resistant (XDR) TB and the need to contain infectious diseases such as XDR TB by extraordinary methods such as quarantine. Such measures, typical of the public health approach to community health problems, involve the limitation of individual rights in the interests of the public good. In this case, the need to contain a costly, highly dangerous and virtually untreatable form of TB by forcibly quarantining patients with this form of TB, were said to outweigh the rights of the patient to autonomy and freedom of movement. Rightly, discussions in South Africa focused on whether the restrictions of the rights of the individual in the interests of the greater good could be justified.
At one level, this is an important debate because it is typical of many other public health conflicts (e.g. in relation to HIV or claims on scarce resources), where individual rights run into conflict with interests that represent a collective or social benefit. Resolving such conflicts in ways that retain respect for human rights whilst advancing public health is important for public health planners, and methods to do so have increasingly emerged in the human rights and public health literature that help public health practitioners negotiate these difficult trade-offs. Thus, in considering whether a limitation on individual autonomy could be justified in the public interest, one would expect that:
- the objective of the policy, such as quarantine, has an objective of legitimate interest and is provided for in terms of a due legal process;
- the policy will be effective in realising that objective;
- the policy is strictly necessary in a democratic society to achieve that objective;
- there are no less intrusive means available to achieve the same objective; and
- the policy’s application is not arbitrary, discriminatory or unreasonable.
Often many public health measures are applied routinely without careful reflection as to whether these criteria are met. Calls for HIV notification, for example, are often made without clear policy objectives, or, where objectives are intended, without any evidence that notification will meet these objectives better than any other methods that are less restrictive of individual autonomy.
However, it is the case that, under certain circumstances, and given certain requirements being met, limiting rights for the public interest can well be justified in terms of international human rights law. Indeed, the limitation of rights may well be viewed differently when one realises that states have obligations imposed by international human rights law to positively realise various obligations to control the spread of infectious diseases (ICESCR, article 12) and to meet requirements for general welfare (ICCPR, article 4).
However, on another level, the public health objective itself is often the expression of a rights obligation of government to realise, for example, an environment not harmful to health (Section 24 of South Africa’s Bill of Rights), or the right of access to health care. Such socio-economic rights obligations are themselves necessarily collective in nature, and the trade off is not so much between individual civil liberties and public health objectives, but between different kinds of rights, such as individualist rights to autonomy, and social rights such as the those relating to health care access or a safe environment, both of which are needed to realise health. Protecting individual autonomy is important for the effectiveness of treatment programmes to ensure patient adherence and build trust in the health service, as much as social measures being required to control the spread of infectious diseases.
Popular misconceptions of rights as being solely or predominantly about civil liberties and formal parliamentary democracy have been fostered by a combination of the ascendance of neo-liberal economic policies in international policy making, as well as the unopposed exercise of power by the USA and its allies in the post-Cold War period in ways that entrench narrow individualist views of rights. Indeed, recognition of the indivisibility of rights and the equal importance of socio-economic entitlements and equity run counter to market-oriented development policies fostered by international development agencies.
Thirdly, human rights are not just about limits to state power but also speak to realising human potential in ways that confer agency.
When faced with public outcry or a health emergency, public health responses frequently fall back on traditional population interventions that obviate any role for individual and community action. The resort to autocratic traditions of central command and control has a strong anti-democratic history in public health and is based on a deep suspicion that humans can be trusted to make decisions in their own collective interest. It is not surprising, therefore, that many of the pioneering anti-smoking public health measures originated in the health programmes of Germany’s Nazi government and were entirely compatible with the ferociously anti-democratic and inhumane ideology of the Nazi regime. What a human rights approach brings to public health, therefore, is to ensure that social justice is a counterbalance to unchallenged utilitarianism, and that checks on power serve to protect the vulnerable, in ways that confer agency on communities to determine the policies and programmes that affect their health.
Increasingly, human rights advocates are realising that the sources of power in society who must be held accountable are not just states, but non-state actors, including multilateral agencies and multinational corporations whose de facto control of resources determines access to the conditions required for health to a far greater extent than does that of many states. International human rights law is increasingly providing “soft” law guidance through issuing of codes of conduct, norms and standards to ensure non-state actor accountability for human rights. Given that human rights are a product of developmental struggles, these frameworks will only be translated into meaningful instruments for accountability through strong civil society pressure on governments to turn such codes and standards into law.
Rights are not just about empowering vulnerable groups, but are themselves the products of contestation of power, at local, national and international level. And where power is contested, we should expect that the products of this contestation will reflect the relative balance of forces of different actors. For this reason, the exclusive emphasis on good governance, parliamentary democracy and civil liberties that has emerged as the dominant paradigm in some development discourses driven by Western governments has ironically contributed to a depoliticisation of rights and of development, because it strips struggles for health of any dimensions that challenge power imbalances – at local, regional and international levels. Yet power imbalances are what underlie health inequalities. This has led many to question “Why rights, why rights now?” since when the language of rights becomes denuded of power, it is turned into a technical exercise of compliance with norms.
Unchallenged, therefore, we should not be so naïve as to imagine that human rights will of necessity benefit poor people, poor communities or poor countries. Rather, by using and shaping rights towards pro-poor choices, human rights become transformative rather than simply easing human suffering. When human rights discourses, for example, begin to challenge and overturn obstacles posed by trade commitments to the realisation of the right to health, then the transformative nature of human rights emerges.
In this paradigm, the role of civil society organisation (CSOs) is absolutely central to realizing the agency that makes human rights approaches transformative. Yet many CSOs undertaking work in the health sector may 'do' human rights work, but are often not aware of the rights implications of their work on the ground. Is 'doing' human rights enhanced by 'acting' (i.e. conscious awareness of) human rights as well? Pilot research in the Western Cape with three health CSOs points to the multiplicative effect that a rights paradigm adds to their impact. By framing (health) needs as rights to which duty-bearers can be held accountable, not only is the demand for pro-poor services strengthened but beneficiaries of these services are enabled to be active agents in securing the conditions for their health, rather than passive recipients of state or NGO services. Moreover, placing demands in a right framework challenges service providers to see their role as realising states’ human rights obligations rather than simply delivering services. It is particularly in the field of socio-economic rights that the duality of service provision as fulfillment of human rights is evident and where it is clearest that human rights are more than just civil liberties.
CSOs engaging with rights approaches can build much stronger advocacy through sharing experiences and learning best practice. EQUINET, through its health rights theme, plans to explore the establishment of a learning network for CSOs in the region using rights approaches as a mechanism for enhancing civil society participation in the development of national health systems that are comprehensive, people-led and people-centred. We invite participation from CSOs and activists throughout the region in developing this network and look forward to your input and contribution to this debate.
Please send feedback or queries on the issues raised in this briefing to the EQUINET secretariat, email admin@equinetafrica.org for attention to School of Public Health, University of Cape Town, Leslie London. Further information and publication on EQUINET work on health rights as a tool for health equity is available at the EQUINET website at www.equinetafrica.org.
In 2000/1 South Africa endured a cholera epidemic that spread throughout the eastern coastal region and to other provinces. It resulted in 265 deaths in five provinces and 117,147 people, mostly in the KwaZulu-Natal province, were infected. The epidemic was, according to the World Health Organization, the biggest such outbreak in Africa for the reporting period.
According to rural development researchers and the South African government, the policies of cost recovery had disadvantaged those for whom even a small charge of about R20 a month was too much. At its epicentre, those who could not afford new charges implemented in August 2000 were returning to traditional and untreated water sources and were falling victim to the disease.
The government declared the cholera epidemic an emergency and promised to provide a free six kilolitres of water to every household every month. A Municipal Services Project Occasional Paper 10, “Still Paying the Price: Revisiting the Cholera Epidemic of 2000–2001 in South Africa” examined the extent to which the response to the epidemic has led to sustained provision of safe water and improved sanitation to the poor. The evidence presented in the report suggests that there is a clear relationship between cost recovery for water, indifferent management leading to interruptions in supply, and vandalism.
In two communities - one at Nqutshini, a small settlement near the town of Empangeni on the banks of the Mhlatuzi River; and the other at Nkobongo, a developing low-cost housing area with continued informal settlements near Ballito, 40km north of Durban - there was some concealment and denial of the disease because of the stigma it carries.
In a number of cases where people fell ill, the family members were uncertain how to respond. Often the cholera victim tried to conceal and deny the disease, and this led to significant delays in seeking treatment. In one instance, a young girl died after hiding her symptoms for some time; in another, an older man had to be heavily persuaded before going to the hospital. The stigma associated with cholera complicated the acceptance of the need to avoid using river water, to treat this water, and, if sick, to seek medical assistance.
There were varying responses to the messages put out by the authorities on radio and television and carried by the Community Health Workers. Many in Nqutshini found it difficult to acknowledge that the river, from which they had always collected water, should be the carrier of disease. Some accepted that the water they were collecting from the river may be contaminated and need treatment, but others did not. Some saw the warnings against using river water as a way of forcing people to pay the monthly charges. It appears that for a period water was treated with Jik (bleach) by many, but this dropped off rapidly when the bleach was no longer available for free.
Scepticism about the official view was also associated with ideas reflecting a view of hostile external forces aiming to undermine the community, e.g. the belief by some that whites were spreading the disease through low-flying aeroplanes. In all cases, the MSP report on the epidemic presents vivid personal recollections of those who were afflicted, the dread it evoked, and the speed at which people’s health declined.
Comparisons between conditions during the epidemic in 2000/1 and at the time of fieldwork in 2003 revealed a number of improvements: Most people now accessed piped water closer to their residence or through yard connections and most used Ventilated Improved Privies (VIPs). Most people at the time of the survey felt their water to be safe to drink and did not treat the water.
However, there were ongoing complaints of frequent interruptions in the water supply through vandalism, burst pipes and for non-payment. In the two communities, the state was not providing Free Basic Water as promised, although the communities are both poor and thus generally vulnerable to cholera. At Nqutshini piped water was not flowing at all. Partly because of the dysfunctional water supplies, there was increased water storage by community members - an additional factor associated with cholera.
The incidence of diarrhoea among children in the household was found to be associated with extreme poverty, as were problems with accessing sufficient water, the ability to pay for water and the household having prior experience of cholera. All these factors - in particular the continued cycle of water-related disease in households over time - point to poor health conditions and continued vulnerability to disease among those living in extreme poverty.
The government’s policy of Free Basic Water has been unevenly implemented and greater attention needs to be given to meeting the needs of the rural poor and those in poor peri-urban communities who would most benefit from its provision. Poor communities need a reliable water service, which requires better municipal management. Interruptions lead to long storage of water, which poses a health risk to those who consume this water. Communities and households with a prior experience of water related diseases seem most vulnerable to recurrence. Health and municipal authorities should give priority to those communities with a history of water-related disease to end the cycle of disease.
The Municipal Services Project is a multipartner research, policy and educational initiative examining the restructuring of municipal sservices in southern Africa. See http://www.queensu.ca/msp/ to contact the project at Rhodes University South Africa to obtain copies of the full report.
Sub-Saharan Africa is the only region in the world where the absolute number and proportion of under-nourished children has increased in the last decade. East Africa is the sub-region experiencing the largest increases in numbers of underweight children –projected to increase by 36% from 1990 to 2005. Findings for stunting (chronic under-nutrition) and wasting (acute under-nutrition) are similar. Under-nutrition is the underlying cause of over half of child deaths. Even mild to moderate malnutrition can lead to significant deficits in cognitive and physical development.
One reason for the dismal nutritional status of children in Africa is the continual lack of food for many in the region. In less than four decades, Sub-Saharan Africa has been transformed from a continent that was a net exporter of food to one that is now heavily dependent on food imports. According to the Food and Agricultural Organisation, Africa’s food imports have risen from 8% in 1985 to 18% of world imports in 2001. A decline in agricultural and rural investment in Africa has led to a 12% decline in agricultural productivity for the workers in the region in the 1990s. Any growth in agricultural output has thus been achieved mostly from expanding the area under cultivation.
The United Nations Millenium Development Goals Hunger Task Team in 2004 summarised the consequences of this path to meeting food needs:
“Expanding the area under food production is inherently unsustainable, as the supply of new lands in densely populated areas of Africa is largely exhausted or must be maintained as natural systems for biodiversity conservation and other ecological services. The first effect in Africa and elsewhere in the tropics has been to expand into land that was previously available for fallows. Leaving land fallow allows land under cultivation the necessary time to recover from the effects of the crops taking nutrients from the soil. As a result of the reduction or elimination of fallows, soil fertility has fallen dramatically in many places, and yields are reducing with time. As the land becomes exhausted, there develops a serious tendency to continually sub-divide land among family members, which leads to smallholdings that are too small to produce a family’s food”.
Significantly, the yields of most important food grains, tubers and legumes (maize, millet, sorghum, yams, cassava and groundnuts) in most African countries are no higher today than in 1980. The environmental impacts of deforestation and drought, floods and the loss of topsoil are being compounded by the lack of investment. Only about 4% of land under cultivation in Africa is irrigated. This compares with 14% in Latin America and the Caribbean, a region with similar population densities and resource endowments. Fertilizer application is 15% lower today than in 1980. The number of tractors per worker is 25% lower than in 1980 and the lowest in the world. Africa’s share of total world agricultural trade fell from 8% in 1965 to 3% in 1996.
However, poor food security or poverty alone is not the whole story. Otherwise how does one explain the experience of many countries and populations that managed to achieve significant reductions in malnutrition before similar reductions in poverty? How does one explain the presence of malnutrition in situations where food is widely available? If one compares, for example, the experience in one region of Sri Lanka, Indonesia, the Philippines and Thailand, in the 1980s and 1990s, Sri Lanka and Thailand showed rapid improvement in nutrition, Indonesia showed slower but consistent improvement, and the Philippines little progress. Malnutrition in Latin America decreased from about 21% in 1970 to 7.2% in 1997, while income poverty decreased by only about 1% over the same time period.
Clearly reducing malnutrition is not solely dependent on increases in income. Gains in Latin America are attributed to good care practices (such as improved complementary feeding) access to basic health services, including family planning, safe water and sanitation and to women’s education and the cash resources they control.
Policies providing for female education, social safety nets, affordable food and public health services have contributed to improvements in nutrition even with minimal changes in poverty levels. In Sri Lanka, high levels of female education have been linked to improved child nutrition and child survival. Sri Lanka’s impressive performance in nutrition is also attributed to the establishment of social safety nets, especially the free or heavily subsidised distribution of rice, providing a minimum consumption floor. More recently, Save the Children UK in 2004 pointed to the universal, equitable and efficient public health system in Sri Lanka as an important reason for the low levels of maternal and child mortality in the country. Thailand incorporated nutrition as an important part of its National Economic and Social Development Plan (NESDP). This led to the establishment of an extensive community-based network of village health communicators and volunteers with existing village committees and leaders. These groups focus in communities on the fulfilment of basic needs such as optimal nutrition, provide education for this and monitor progress this through community-based growth monitoring.
A similar mobilisation of communities, health systems and national resources is required if we are to make a start in combating childhood malnutrition in Africa. This is an essential step if there is to be sustainable development in the region. Co-ordinated by the Health Science Research Council, EQUINET has embarked on a programme in east and southern Africa to collect and share information on case studies of how health systems address the wider social and economic factors affecting nutrition and lever action on these factors.
Please send feedback or queries on the issues raised in this briefing to the EQUINET secretariat email admin@equinetafrica.org. EQUINET work on food security and nutrition is available at the EQUINET website at www.equinetafrica.org. Work by the Medical Research Council of South Africa (MRC) is available at www.mrc.ac.za.
Developing countries took several initiatives at the World Health Organisation's (WHO's) 59th World Health Assembly (WHA) in May 2006 to raise the need for WHO more strongly assert its global role in protecting health in the global economy.
A resolution was passed to increase coordination between WHO and the World Trade Organisation (WTO) on Trade and Health. It mandated the WHO to assist countries that are negotiating trade agreements that have an impact on their health sectors. Ministers at the East, Central and Southern African Health Community 42nd Regional Health Minister’s Conference in February 2006 called for such training for government and civil society to facilitate better understanding of the TRIPs agreement. Towards this EQUINET has developed a training toolkit on trade and health and carried out pilot workshops in Malawi, Zimbabwe and Tanzania. These confirm the call for greater support to country teams in negotiating new issues on trade and health. Countries are currently dealing with the General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS) and the implementation of flexibilities under the WTO's Trade Related Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPs) agreement. TRIPs flexibilities relate to access to patented medicines or legally produced generics. The GATS deals with the liberalisation of health and health related services and has implications for cost recovery, cross subsidisation, health insurance, the regulation of commercial or competitive health services and indirectly related sectors like distribution.
Critics of the GATS have, for example, pointed out that it can and has limited the ability of governments to regulate health services towards the necessary cross subsidies and equity measures needed to promote universal access. EQUINET has resolved in its past forums that in a situation of high inequality in access to services, governments should enjoy full flexibility to regulate their health sectors in the public interest, unconstrained by WTO disciplines. The WTO Secretariat countered such criticisms in a publication “GATS - Fact and Fiction”, responding that countries were free to make commitments only in sectors they choose and could therefore limit liberalisation. This poses a problem for countries like Zambia who have already committed their health services in GATS, and may now want to regulate areas of health service provision. A ruling in April 2004 of the WTO's dispute settlement body in a case between the US and Mexico raises even greater concerns for countries like Zambia, as the dispute settlement body decided that the right of a country to promote development was not as important as its commitments to trade in services under the GATS.
In the TRIPs negotiations, flexibilities for developing countries for local production or import of pharmaceuticals under compulsory licenses have also led to relatively stiff resistance to proposals for improved flexibilities. Countries have also had to deal with bilateral trade agreements that erode these flexibilities. Some Latin American ministers at the WHA made a separate statement saying that TRIPs obligations should not be increased under bilateral/regional agreements. At the same time, the ECSA Regional Health Ministers noted that countries in the region still need to fully utilize these flexibilities and embed them in their national laws.
WHO clearly has significant challenges to address to promote health under WTO agreements. The mandate of the Trade and Health resolution is broad and will need to be closely monitored to ensure that the co-ordination promotes public health priorities and challenges the WTO's stronghold in health, particularly for developing countries.
One area of ground work for this has been in the WHO Commission for Intellectual Property Rights and Innovation in Public Health. The commission report was tabled at the WHA and made a number of recommendations on the IPR system for health, including that needs-driven health research should follow public health and development priorities; and promote innovation to develop solutions to health problems.
Parallel to this report an Intergovernmental Working Group was established by a resolution of the WHA, proposed by Kenya and Brazil. The proposal responded to the limitations of the current risk-reward innovation system of IPRs. This profit driven model fails to provide incentives for research into diseases affecting developing countries. Because the expectation of profit is limited in these “neglected diseases,” drugs are not researched and developed. The Working Group was mandated to produce a strategy and action plan on ways of promoting research for the prevention and management of these diseases and to examine the impact of this research on public health. This too will be an area where inputs from Africa will be important, given the extreme inequities that exist between public health burden and access to the technologies, diagnostics and drugs to prevent and manage disease.
African countries again raised the issue of the “brain drain” at the WHA, and the effect it has on their ability to cope with health demands. They requested compensation and ethical recruitment practices in sometimes tense debates. The African proposals were contested by the some developed countries, including those recruiting and receiving health personnel from Africa. The debates were not resolved, and the WHA resolution adopted committed rich countries to increase funding for health worker education in developing countries, inadequately addressing the wider demand for mechanisms that fairly and sustainably address perverse subsidies and enable African health sectors to value and retain their own health workers. At the same time, countries in the region need to be aware of the implications of the commitments they make under the GATS agreement on the movement of persons. Countries that make commitments that include liberalising the movement of people in the health sector may weaken their claims to compensation for that movement. Given the significant impact the shortfall in health workers is having in access to health care in east and southern Africa, we need bolder, more challenging global arrangements to manage issues of migration and resource transfers than have been the case to date.
Please send feedback or queries on the issues raised in this briefing to the EQUINET secretariat at TARSC, email admin@equinetafrica.org and to SEATINI (www.seatini.org). EQUINET work on health equity in economic and trade policy is available at the EQUINET website at www.equinetafrica.org.
Compared to 20 years ago in Kenya, people live for ten years less on average, more children die in infancy and a greater proportion of those who survive face stunting. Why? Soren Ambrose makes a case for holding the International Monetary Fund (IMF) responsible, arguing that the institution's obsession with low inflation rates - one of the foundations of trade liberalization - starves economies and hurts the poor.
On March 6, Kenya's Assistant Minister for Health, Enock Kibunguchy, told the press that Kenya urgently needs to hire 10,000 additional professionals in the public health sector, blurting out: “We have to put our foot down and employ. We can tell the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank to go to hell.”
These are strong words for a high-ranking government official to put on record regarding the most powerful international financial institutions (IFIs), and in particular the IMF, a body whose power extends to being able to call for the withdrawal of virtually all external assistance to a country.
Minister of Health Charity Ngilu had in fact been rumored to have made similar accusations in meetings with IMF officials and civil society representatives; since Kibunguchy's declaration she has confirmed she shares his view. Similar allegations have also been made by several civil society organizations focused on the IMF and on health rights. Indeed, in the last two years a number of organizations have identified IMF restrictions as a serious disincentive to hiring desperately-needed health professionals not only in Kenya, but in many other African and Global South countries as well.
Specific IMF policies, in particular the low ceilings it sets for inflation rates and wage expenditures in borrowing countries, are demonstrably illogical and detrimental. Together with the dubious defense the IMF mounts for maintaining such restrictions, cases like Kenya's provide a strong argument that those controlling the IMF should re-examine the restrictions it places on borrowing governments. The logic of demanding continual decreases in public wage bills is likewise suspect, as are the IMF's routine inflation targets. With increased funding from new sources, improved standards of living are within reach of even the most impoverished countries, if only the IMF would allow it.
The Health Care Crisis
Kenya's health care crisis has been 20 years in the making. Its dimensions are spelled out in the 2004 Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper (PRSP) - a government document written in consultation with the IMF and World Bank and approved by both bodies' boards. Life expectancy declined from 57 in 1986 to 47 in 2000; infant mortality increased from 62 per thousand in 1993 to 78 per thousand in 2003; and under-five mortality rose from 96 per thousand births to 114 per thousand in the same period. The percentage of children with stunted growth increased from 29% in 1993 to 31% in 2003, and the percentage of Kenya's children who are fully-vaccinated dropped from 79% in 1993 to 52% in 2003.
Why this deterioration? As in most African countries, Kenya's health care system was hit hard by the “structural adjustment” policies imposed by the IMF and World Bank as conditions on loans and as prerequisites for getting IFI approval of the country's economic policies. Those policies were introduced in the 1980s, and have left a lasting mark on Kenya's health. As usual with such programs, the emphasis was on cutting budget expenditures. As a result, local health clinics and dispensaries had fewer supplies and medicines, and user fees became more common. The public hospitals saw their standard of care deteriorate, increasing pressure on the largest public facility, Kenyatta National Hospital in Nairobi. As a consequence, that hospital, once the leading health facility in East Africa, began, like so many other African hospitals, to ask patients' families to provide outside food, medicine, and medical supplies. Most beds at Kenyatta and the regional and local hospitals accommodated two patients. Professional staff have taken jobs - some part-time, some full-time, at private healthcare facilities, or migrated to Europe or North America in search of better pay.
An October 2005 communication from an NGO coalition to the November 2005 “High Level Forum on Health MDGs (Millennium Development Goals)” notes that “between 1991 and 2003, the [Kenyan] government reduced its work force by 30%” - cuts that hit the health sector particularly hard.[3] For the period between 2000 and 2002 alone, the government was scheduled to lay off 5,300 health staff.
Those requirements were externally imposed. A World Bank Group document from November 2003, written to justify waiving a loan condition calling for a workforce reduction, notes: “This condition required retrenching 32,000 personnel from civil service over a period of two years. In practice, 23,448 civil servants were retrenched in 2000/01 before the program was interrupted by lawsuits. A specific commitment in the updated [agreement] is to reduce the size of the civil service by 5,000 per year through natural attrition.” The very same document supports Assistant Minister Kibunguchy's assessment of the sector's current needs - “the health sector currently experiences a staff shortage of about 10,000 health workers.” The document, however, draws no connection between the shortage and the insistence on cutting more workers.
The impact of the layoffs and budget slashing in the health sector over the last 15 years was cited recently by Member of Parliament Alfred Nderitu as the primary motivation for his motion of censure against the IMF and World Bank in the Kenyan Parliament. His initiative would insist that any future loans from the institutions get Parliamentary approval.
Clinics Without Nurses
Many African countries have shortages of medical staff because of lack of training capacity; in Kenya this is not the case. Thousands are unemployed or underemployed, eager to take up full time positions.
Both the Kenyan government and the IFIs regularly announce that health spending will increase substantially. With all these promises of increased resources for health care, with the World Bank's acknowledgement of a staff shortage, and with all those unemployed nurses, one might expect that the government would waste no time in hiring the thousands of nurses Kenya so desperately needs. And indeed, frequent promises are made by government officials to that effect. But the promises are almost never kept.
According to the Chief Economist in the Ministry of Health, S.N. Muchiri, the reason is that while the IFIs support increased expenditures on health, they forbid spending that money to pay staff wages. This is accomplished through insisting on a ceiling on wage expenditures; in Kenya, the targets are 8.5% of GDP in 2006 and 7.2% by 2008. The IMF doesn't specify that hiring in the health sector specifically must be limited, but when the entire wage bill must be suppressed, the chances of hiring the personnel needed are slim indeed.
So when IFI staffers call for more funding for clinics, as they do in their critique of the government's draft PRSP, they mean buildings, equipment, and medicine. Unfortunately, personnel are required to run the clinics. It is the choice by those institutions to prioritize targets for reduced spending on public salaries and on inflation, says Muchiri, that prevents Kenya from hiring health workers.
Muchiri provides valuable “inside” confirmation of charges made with increasing intensity by civil society organizations over the last two years. Advocates point out that while recent funding initiatives like the Global Fund for AIDS, Tuberculosis & Malaria and PEPFAR have made stemming the most critical health crises in Africa more possible, the IMF's power over borrowers' economic policy and its narrow focus on keeping inflation and payrolls as low as possible is actively discouraging governments from putting the available funds to use.
Numbers, Not People
On one level, it seems like commonsense for an organization like the IMF to seek out ways in which governments can reduce the amount spent on salaries, especially in countries like Kenya, which have had troubles with “ghost employees” on public payrolls in the past. But the self-defeating nature of this quest quickly becomes apparent. If the government were simply expected to identify and eliminate ghost employees, that would obviously lighten the government's burden and enable it to target its resources more wisely.
But the IMF's conditions deal with bottom-line expenditures, not with going to the root of the problem. Kenya's PRSP spells out the implications: “…achieving the 8.5 percent target by 2005/06 will require that any awards to be provided to the civil servants or any additional awards will be matched by a proportionate downsizing of the civil service.” Any hiring of nurses, for example, would require that some other public employees be eliminated - regardless of how much the nurses may be needed, or how vital the other positions may be. Indiscriminate targeting like this only demonstrates the prioritizing of abstract economic statistical standards over real-life outcomes, including those most likely to have a positive material impact on poverty and on contributing to the overall health of both Kenya's population and the economy.
So if the health budget is to rise - as both the IFIs and the government repeat often - then the PRSP must remind us that: “The fiscal strategy assumes that these health expenditures will be focused on non-wage non-transfer expenditures and will thus enable the rapid increase in basic health services.” Indeed, Muchiri reports that funds are often available for facilities or supplies, but not for staff. The result is that more people may seek out health services, but the ministry will actually be less able to provide them because of lack of personnel to administer the drugs or operate the machinery.
Inflation, Inflation, Inflation
But why does the IMF, with its power to exclude a country from the global economy by declaring it “off-track,” insist on reducing government payrolls? Adding employees to the government payroll, especially if accomplished with aid money, is considered by orthodox economists like those at the IMF to increase inflationary pressures in a developing country. And an increase in inflation is anathema to the IMF.
The IMF quite openly prioritizes inflation targeting over almost any other factor in the countries where it works. Pressed on the question, as they have been in the debate over health spending, its officials will invariably respond that inflation is a “tax” that hits the poor the hardest.
But is that true? Anis Chowdhury points out that:
“The poor have very limited financial assets; they are largely net financial debtors. Thus inflation can benefit the poor by reducing the real value of their financial debt. Meanwhile, the IMF's cure for inflation - raising interest rates - can actually harm the poor because this increases the servicing costs of their current debts. The poor fare worse when unemployment rises and persists, especially when there is no adequate safety net or social security system. At the same time, the real value of their household debt rises with falling inflation rates. Hence the poor have more reason to be averse to unemployment and less averse to inflation than the elite in society."
After this seemingly obvious point is made, it seems only too easy to point out that those who stand to lose the most from inflation are those who hold large amounts of money - financiers, investors, bankers. Yes, there are risks to the poor in high and/or persistent inflation, but increases in inflation below a certain point are far more likely to cause pain to those whose incomes depend on relatively minor fluctuations in currency values. For the impoverished, as Chowdhury explains, such increases in inflation are likely to be more beneficial than harmful.
As is so often the case, it is easiest to discern the interests of policy-makers not from their rhetoric, but from whose interests are most vigorously protected by their policies - by who “wins” as a result. The IMF's longtime prioritization of inflation over all else lends weight to those who accuse it of using its powers to protect the interests of the wealthy over those of the impoverished, regardless of their rhetoric that maintains the reverse.
IMF official Andy Berg recently admitted as much: “Higher inflation tax[es] people who hold cash or whose nominal incomes are fixed.” But Berg's next sentence restores IMF ideology, and at the same time exposes its flimsiness: “And this tax discourages private investment and tends to fall on those least able to adapt - in other words the poor.” Berg relocates the pain from the rich to the poor, but offers no logic for that move.
Drawing a Reasonable Line on Inflation
To challenge the IMF, the question must be where to draw the line - at what point, to use Berg's phrase, is “inflation out of control,” or at risk of spinning out of control? Berg says “in poor countries the danger point is somewhere between 5 and 10 percent.” The good news is that this figure is actually less conservative than the standard used in most IMF programs. In most countries with IMF loans, the conditions call for inflation to decline and stay below five percent.
Few economists outside the IMF opt for a level as low even as 10% in defining a healthy rate of inflation for a growing economy in a developing country. Terry McKinley, an economist with the United Nations Development Program (UNDP), declares: “As long as current revenue covers current expenditures, governments can usefully borrow to finance [social] investment. […] Fiscal deficits should remain sustainable as ensuing growth boosts revenue collection. The resultant growth of productive capacities will keep inflation moderate - namely, within a 15 percent rate per year.”
There is no room for neutrality in this debate. Adhering to IMF standards in order to avoid trouble will, according to McKinley, likely sabotage any hope of genuine development:
“Moderate inflation can, in fact, be compatible with growth. But low inflation can be as harmful as high inflation. When low-inflation policies keep the economy mired in stagnation or drive it into recession, the poor lose out, often for years thereafter, as their meager stocks of wealth are wiped out or their human capabilities seriously impaired. […] Without jobs and income, people cannot benefit from price stability.”
Tactfully avoiding mentioning the IMF by name, McKinley argues: “The new 'politically correct' justification for minimizing inflation is that it hurts the poor. However, this misreads the facts: very high, destabilizing inflation (above 40 per cent) definitely hurts the poor; and very low inflation (below 5 per cent) can also harm their interests when it impedes growth and employment.”
Rick Rowden points out that Latin American countries and “East Asian tigers” like South Korea grew rapidly despite inflation rates of around 20%. But that was before the IMF moved into the development world in the 1980s, and re-wrote the rules - without any definitive evidence to support their claim that doing so was advantageous to the poor.
The IMF appears to be caught in a classic case of “fighting the last battle.” When the IMF started lending to developing countries in the early 1980s, they were afflicted with astronomical, runaway inflation. It still apparently believes that hyperinflation is the most dangerous threat. But hyperinflation has been eliminated almost everywhere (apart from crisis or pariah countries like Zimbabwe); indeed most developing countries now have inflation rates well below 10%, and many below 5%. This is largely as a result of the IMF's hyper-vigilance over the last 25 years. The problem today is not hyperinflation, but IMF-induced stagnation.
More and more economists - outside the IMF - are taking a more complex view of growth and inflation. Rather than insisting that a country have a demonstrated “absorptive capacity” before increasing the flow of revenues, they look at the likely impact of increased flows. In the case of increased spending on health care, not only is employment created (if wage ceilings are set aside), but the population's overall economic capacity improves, and private-sector activity, rather than being discouraged by public funds, is spurred by the increasing availability of resources.
Muchiri, in Kenya's Health Ministry, concurs with McKinley's positions on inflation targeting, and with the view that public spending, especially on healthcare, will encourage growth. He acknowledges that his government has committed to a low inflation target - its “Letter of Intent” to the IMF states: “The monetary program for 2004/05 is designed to reduce underlying inflation to 3.5 percent.” And thus far Kenya seems to be meeting that goal.
But, says Muchiri: “3.5 percent is too low for an economy that is supposed to grow by 5 percent. A certain level of inflation is healthy - you can't grow otherwise.” This recognition moves Muchiri to criticize officials of a nearby country who have told him they must limit expenditures on health care - even refusing funds from the GFTAM - in order to prevent any risk of inflation rising. That line of thinking is clearly reflected in the recent statements by Kibunguchy and Ngilu.
But Finance Ministers who have committed to the IMF's inflation targets, and in many cases made those targets the centerpiece of their macroeconomic policy, are deeply reluctant to do anything that might raise that rate. Not only would doing so risk IMF disapproval and blacklisting, but it would also be seen as reversing a position they have publicly, and politically, committed to. Until this logjam is broken, a higher quality of life - even life itself - will continue to elude many thousands.
Muchiri counts as a significant victory the recent concession made by the IMF, after substantial negotiations, that Kenya could hire more health professionals if it could find donors willing to provide extra funds who themselves were comfortable with the impacts - economic and otherwise - that hiring additional health staff might have. It is this concession that recently allowed Kenya to announce that it will use funds from the Clinton Foundation, PEPFAR, and the GFATM to hire upwards of two thousand new nurses and other health professionals. Unlike with previous pledges, advertisements for the positions are now appearing in newspapers.
But the very existence of these policies, and the fact that he must invest so much in winning exceptions to them, cause Muchiri to reflect on his experiences of watching mothers and children die in hospitals for lack of surgeons or a lack of capacity to offer preventive care, and speculate that the IMF and World Bank could reasonably be charged with genocide. “The only difference from what happened in Rwanda is they don't use pangas [machetes]. They use policies.”
Reproduced with permission from the author from Pambazuka news 1 June 2006. http://www.pambazuka.org/en/category/features/34800